Can one say that US politicians are more independent from their parties than others?

The name of the pictureThe name of the pictureThe name of the pictureClash Royale CLAN TAG#URR8PPP











up vote
24
down vote

favorite
4












On this question, a user commented:




It should be noted that the US has the weakest political parties among modern democracies - that is, US politician are way more independent from their parties than their counterparts abroad (in Europe or elsewhere). Therefore, the founding fathers did succeed in part in preventing political parties.




How would one evaluate this claim? It seems like there could be numbers out there that show how often representatives break from their parties, and whether American politicians do more frequently.



I'm assuming the commenters was discussing members of the US Congress.










share|improve this question

















  • 2




    You'd probably have to dig up data from all over the place and collate it yourself. Here's a start: washingtonpost.com/news/the-fix/wp/2015/06/11/…
    – user1530
    Aug 28 at 20:33






  • 10




    But you also need to take context into play. In the US, there really are only 2 parties. Compared to say some European states which may have a half dozen or more. Based only on that, US politicians would be more likely to vote against their party given the reduced number of 'buckets' they can belong to. In other words, it may not be that US politicians are more independent of their parties, but rather with only two parties, their own agendas are less likely to align as well as in countries with many parties.
    – user1530
    Aug 28 at 20:34











  • Half dozen? That is not particularly much. Some have like 20.
    – mathreadler
    Aug 30 at 7:35











  • @blip You would probably want to normalize the inner party variances somehow with the size of the party (number of politicians/members) to really compare them. A single member party like the PVV in the Netherlands probably shows 100% alignment of party and its politician(s).
    – Trilarion
    Aug 30 at 11:03






  • 1




    @blip Interesting observation. And this leads to an obvious hint as to where we can find even more conflicting votes within a party: one-party systems. I'm not sure where (and if) voting history of the Chinese NPC is available, but wouldn't be surprised if some decisions split votes significantly.
    – Alice
    Aug 30 at 14:10














up vote
24
down vote

favorite
4












On this question, a user commented:




It should be noted that the US has the weakest political parties among modern democracies - that is, US politician are way more independent from their parties than their counterparts abroad (in Europe or elsewhere). Therefore, the founding fathers did succeed in part in preventing political parties.




How would one evaluate this claim? It seems like there could be numbers out there that show how often representatives break from their parties, and whether American politicians do more frequently.



I'm assuming the commenters was discussing members of the US Congress.










share|improve this question

















  • 2




    You'd probably have to dig up data from all over the place and collate it yourself. Here's a start: washingtonpost.com/news/the-fix/wp/2015/06/11/…
    – user1530
    Aug 28 at 20:33






  • 10




    But you also need to take context into play. In the US, there really are only 2 parties. Compared to say some European states which may have a half dozen or more. Based only on that, US politicians would be more likely to vote against their party given the reduced number of 'buckets' they can belong to. In other words, it may not be that US politicians are more independent of their parties, but rather with only two parties, their own agendas are less likely to align as well as in countries with many parties.
    – user1530
    Aug 28 at 20:34











  • Half dozen? That is not particularly much. Some have like 20.
    – mathreadler
    Aug 30 at 7:35











  • @blip You would probably want to normalize the inner party variances somehow with the size of the party (number of politicians/members) to really compare them. A single member party like the PVV in the Netherlands probably shows 100% alignment of party and its politician(s).
    – Trilarion
    Aug 30 at 11:03






  • 1




    @blip Interesting observation. And this leads to an obvious hint as to where we can find even more conflicting votes within a party: one-party systems. I'm not sure where (and if) voting history of the Chinese NPC is available, but wouldn't be surprised if some decisions split votes significantly.
    – Alice
    Aug 30 at 14:10












up vote
24
down vote

favorite
4









up vote
24
down vote

favorite
4






4





On this question, a user commented:




It should be noted that the US has the weakest political parties among modern democracies - that is, US politician are way more independent from their parties than their counterparts abroad (in Europe or elsewhere). Therefore, the founding fathers did succeed in part in preventing political parties.




How would one evaluate this claim? It seems like there could be numbers out there that show how often representatives break from their parties, and whether American politicians do more frequently.



I'm assuming the commenters was discussing members of the US Congress.










share|improve this question













On this question, a user commented:




It should be noted that the US has the weakest political parties among modern democracies - that is, US politician are way more independent from their parties than their counterparts abroad (in Europe or elsewhere). Therefore, the founding fathers did succeed in part in preventing political parties.




How would one evaluate this claim? It seems like there could be numbers out there that show how often representatives break from their parties, and whether American politicians do more frequently.



I'm assuming the commenters was discussing members of the US Congress.







united-states parties






share|improve this question













share|improve this question











share|improve this question




share|improve this question










asked Aug 28 at 20:06









Azor Ahai

1,032617




1,032617







  • 2




    You'd probably have to dig up data from all over the place and collate it yourself. Here's a start: washingtonpost.com/news/the-fix/wp/2015/06/11/…
    – user1530
    Aug 28 at 20:33






  • 10




    But you also need to take context into play. In the US, there really are only 2 parties. Compared to say some European states which may have a half dozen or more. Based only on that, US politicians would be more likely to vote against their party given the reduced number of 'buckets' they can belong to. In other words, it may not be that US politicians are more independent of their parties, but rather with only two parties, their own agendas are less likely to align as well as in countries with many parties.
    – user1530
    Aug 28 at 20:34











  • Half dozen? That is not particularly much. Some have like 20.
    – mathreadler
    Aug 30 at 7:35











  • @blip You would probably want to normalize the inner party variances somehow with the size of the party (number of politicians/members) to really compare them. A single member party like the PVV in the Netherlands probably shows 100% alignment of party and its politician(s).
    – Trilarion
    Aug 30 at 11:03






  • 1




    @blip Interesting observation. And this leads to an obvious hint as to where we can find even more conflicting votes within a party: one-party systems. I'm not sure where (and if) voting history of the Chinese NPC is available, but wouldn't be surprised if some decisions split votes significantly.
    – Alice
    Aug 30 at 14:10












  • 2




    You'd probably have to dig up data from all over the place and collate it yourself. Here's a start: washingtonpost.com/news/the-fix/wp/2015/06/11/…
    – user1530
    Aug 28 at 20:33






  • 10




    But you also need to take context into play. In the US, there really are only 2 parties. Compared to say some European states which may have a half dozen or more. Based only on that, US politicians would be more likely to vote against their party given the reduced number of 'buckets' they can belong to. In other words, it may not be that US politicians are more independent of their parties, but rather with only two parties, their own agendas are less likely to align as well as in countries with many parties.
    – user1530
    Aug 28 at 20:34











  • Half dozen? That is not particularly much. Some have like 20.
    – mathreadler
    Aug 30 at 7:35











  • @blip You would probably want to normalize the inner party variances somehow with the size of the party (number of politicians/members) to really compare them. A single member party like the PVV in the Netherlands probably shows 100% alignment of party and its politician(s).
    – Trilarion
    Aug 30 at 11:03






  • 1




    @blip Interesting observation. And this leads to an obvious hint as to where we can find even more conflicting votes within a party: one-party systems. I'm not sure where (and if) voting history of the Chinese NPC is available, but wouldn't be surprised if some decisions split votes significantly.
    – Alice
    Aug 30 at 14:10







2




2




You'd probably have to dig up data from all over the place and collate it yourself. Here's a start: washingtonpost.com/news/the-fix/wp/2015/06/11/…
– user1530
Aug 28 at 20:33




You'd probably have to dig up data from all over the place and collate it yourself. Here's a start: washingtonpost.com/news/the-fix/wp/2015/06/11/…
– user1530
Aug 28 at 20:33




10




10




But you also need to take context into play. In the US, there really are only 2 parties. Compared to say some European states which may have a half dozen or more. Based only on that, US politicians would be more likely to vote against their party given the reduced number of 'buckets' they can belong to. In other words, it may not be that US politicians are more independent of their parties, but rather with only two parties, their own agendas are less likely to align as well as in countries with many parties.
– user1530
Aug 28 at 20:34





But you also need to take context into play. In the US, there really are only 2 parties. Compared to say some European states which may have a half dozen or more. Based only on that, US politicians would be more likely to vote against their party given the reduced number of 'buckets' they can belong to. In other words, it may not be that US politicians are more independent of their parties, but rather with only two parties, their own agendas are less likely to align as well as in countries with many parties.
– user1530
Aug 28 at 20:34













Half dozen? That is not particularly much. Some have like 20.
– mathreadler
Aug 30 at 7:35





Half dozen? That is not particularly much. Some have like 20.
– mathreadler
Aug 30 at 7:35













@blip You would probably want to normalize the inner party variances somehow with the size of the party (number of politicians/members) to really compare them. A single member party like the PVV in the Netherlands probably shows 100% alignment of party and its politician(s).
– Trilarion
Aug 30 at 11:03




@blip You would probably want to normalize the inner party variances somehow with the size of the party (number of politicians/members) to really compare them. A single member party like the PVV in the Netherlands probably shows 100% alignment of party and its politician(s).
– Trilarion
Aug 30 at 11:03




1




1




@blip Interesting observation. And this leads to an obvious hint as to where we can find even more conflicting votes within a party: one-party systems. I'm not sure where (and if) voting history of the Chinese NPC is available, but wouldn't be surprised if some decisions split votes significantly.
– Alice
Aug 30 at 14:10




@blip Interesting observation. And this leads to an obvious hint as to where we can find even more conflicting votes within a party: one-party systems. I'm not sure where (and if) voting history of the Chinese NPC is available, but wouldn't be surprised if some decisions split votes significantly.
– Alice
Aug 30 at 14:10










3 Answers
3






active

oldest

votes

















up vote
37
down vote













Traditionally, yes, but not much anymore



One way would be to look at how often members of one party vote the same as members of another party. In this 2015 paper published on PLOS One: The Rise of Partisanship and Super-Cooperators in the U.S. House of Representatives, Andris et.al. do just this with data from 1949-2018:




We define a network of over 5 million pairs of representatives, and compare the mutual agreement rates on legislative decisions between two distinct types of pairs: those from the same party and those formed of members from different parties.




In the plot below (figure 1), the authors plot the probability that 2 representatives will vote the same way on a vote, split by whether they belong to the same party (light grey) or different parties (dark grey). As you can see, from 1949 (the first year studied) through 1981, there is substantial overlap between the 2 distributions, meaning that members of the same party often disagree at a similar rate to members of a different party.



Beginning in the 1980s, however, these peaks separate, showing that representatives are becoming more polarized and more likely to vote with their party.



enter image description here



The takeaway from this is that while, traditionally, US politicians were quite willing to break with their parties and work with members of their opposition, this behavior has all but disappeared in recent decades.






share|improve this answer


















  • 9




    I've seen this before, but it doesn't show how much non-Americans break from their party, so I can't make a comparison.
    – Azor Ahai
    Aug 28 at 22:46






  • 2




    I would be interested in that as well, though obviously it depends on the country. I think what we can say from these data is that US politicians' reputation for independence (from party control) is no longer warranted
    – divibisan
    Aug 29 at 0:01






  • 2




    @MatthieuM Interesting idea, at first I thought that that might not make that big of difference, but this data follows a time frame where the two parties basically switched voter bases and candidates. I assume this would have a confusing effect on this type of data and make drawing conclusions about past political unity difficult.
    – Nathan Cooper
    Aug 29 at 12:15






  • 2




    That's not a sign of strong parties, that's a sign of strong partisanship. vox.com/mischiefs-of-faction/2016/11/3/13512362/…
    – David Rice
    Aug 29 at 14:50






  • 3




    I think the question is "How would one evaluate this claim?" not "is the claim valid" to which this is an excellent answer.
    – UKMonkey
    Aug 30 at 12:16

















up vote
5
down vote













Basically this is likely to be true (i.e. that US has more dissent) due to the average effect that "personalized electoral rules" (meaning not running on lists like in continental Europe) and the existence of primary elections in US. From https://www.jstor.org/stable/24886188:




I present an individual level, cross-national analysis of institutional effects on legislators' behavior. To this end, I calculated the percentage of times 6,776 legislators from 180 parties in 30 country-sessions voted against the majority of their party. Using this data, I find support for the assertion that the positive effect of personalized electoral rules on dissent levels is mitigated by centralized selections carried out by party leaders, and similarly that the tendency of democratized selection processes (e.g., primaries) to increase legislators' defection levels is moderated by a party-centered electoral environment.




Alas the paper does not contain the individual country data.



There's one 2015 paper that does make a direct US-Europe contrast, alas in somewhat hard-to-grasp terms:




Moises Ostrogorski once denounced political parties for burying diverse concerns of pluralistic societies under monolithic electoral options. E.E. Schattschneider celebrated them for the same reason: organizing choice and ‘responsible party government’ amid pluralistic complexity. Comparativists have found both dynamics in European legislatures: most European parties exhibit the high average levels of voting unity that Schattschneider’s theory implies, but also display rather Ostrogorskian cycles of discipline, stifling dissent on divisive issues at election time. We use comparativists’ tools to explore the dynamics and normative quality of party unity in the different terrain of the US Congress. We find similar cycles of unity in roll-call voting, but in the American context – with more loosely organized parties, especially historically but still today – Ostrogorskian stifling of dissent operates against a less Schattschneiderian background. In comparative perspective, Congressional parties muffle divisive issues more effectively than they deliver governance, with tenuous implications for representation.




They have some plots of cyclical party discipline in the paper, but these aren't comparative (i.e. US only.) They expand a bit more on their comparison with Europe in text:




Although Ostrogorskian fears might seem to originate from party strength, then,
they may actually be most troubling where parties are weak. The comparative work
that inspired our project shows similar cycles in European parties. Yet these parties
presumably offer more Schattschneiderian benefits in return: very high average
unity means that they retain considerable coherence even in the cycle’s troughs, so
that on many issues they translate electoral unity into responsible government.
When we find similar cycles in a US context with lower average unity – and
especially where parties are weakest, before the 1980s and generally in the Senate –
unity may be more deceptive. The lower the average unity, the more the cycles’
troughs challenge delivery of legislative majorities, and thus the more election-time
peaks represent misleading promises to voters. Especially on issues with the highest
prevailing levels of dissent, where our analysis finds the strongest cycles [...],
parties may serve mainly to remove disruptive questions from electoral competition
(as with EU issues in Europe: Parsons and Weber, 2011). When overall unity across
issues is extremely low – as was long typical in the United States – parties with little
capacity to deliver governance might exist largely to construct rhetorical packages and
obfuscate cross-cutting concerns. Troublingly, we found the strongest cycles of dissent
in parties that should, in principle, be best positioned to deliver on their promises
thanks to electoral success and majority control [...]. Certainly, the
record of US majority parties in enacting major campaign promises is weak – moments
like Obamacare, Newt Gingrich’s Contract with America, or Johnson’s Great Society
are exceptions that prove the rule – and ‘weak Ostrogorskian’ parties may thus share
some of the blame typically attributed to divided government. ‘Responsible party
government’ is especially difficult to deliver in the American context, but unfortunately
it seems that Ostrogorskian muffling is somewhat easier to achieve.




So yes, overall they find "lower average [party] unity" in the US compared to Europe. They also confirm the US historical trend toward higher party unity since the 1980s (the topic of divibisan's answer).



They conclude US party unity has not reached European levels based on Rice index comparisons:




Recently, Congressional parties have become more unified than ever – though still
not like European parties.
Until the 1990s, Congressional politics were largely
understood as the opposite of strong party government (Mayhew, 1974). In an
institutional environment of majoritarian elections in single-member districts,
combined with a separately-elected executive, classic models of legislative representation
emphasized individual candidates and their constituencies (Miller and
Stokes, 1963). This changed as the long North–South realignment rearranged party
lines, and as reforms in the 1970s gave party leaders resources to incentivize
discipline (Rohde, 1991; Stonecash, 2006). From a fragmented arena with party
scores on the Rice index of voting unity below 70 in the 1950s and 1960s, unity
peaked in the 110th Congress (2007–09) at 87.25 for the House of Representatives
(84.85 including the Senate).



Yet American party unity remains modest by European standards. One survey of
European data from the 1990s found Rice index scores that approached perfection,
like mean unity across multiple parties of 99.93 in Denmark, 99.33 in France, 99.25
in the United Kingdom, and 99.06 in Belgium (Depauw and Martin, 2009: 105).




The paper also notes somewhere in its intro that




European and American literatures on legislative behavior that have remained strikingly separate.




... which is something that I discovered myself trying find any comparative papers to answer this question...






share|improve this answer






















  • And neither does the author's massive PhD thesis (in which that paper corresponds to chapter 4). And if anyone is interested, there's another PhD thesis with breakout data for European countries.
    – Fizz
    Aug 29 at 1:01


















up vote
4
down vote













The fact that the US is huge means that politicians from the same party can have different opinions on policy based on regional issues. A Republican from California is going to have strong opinions that differ from a Republican from Texas. From a general standpoint, aside from the primary elections, there is no benefit to joining a political party in the United States unless you intend to run for elected office. Among your average Citizen, registered independent voters (as opposed to the very unnoteworthy Independent Party) are the fastest growing party affiliation in the United States and hold a 42% share of registered voters in the United States, compared to the 29% Democrat share of affiliations and the 25% Republican share (although these aren't their lowest numbers of support, they are pretty close and nadir for each was within the decade).



Most independents identify as leaning towards one party more than another, but all are dissatisfied with the party's pure platform and would rather not be attached to them. The Independent numbers do generally shrink in Presidential Election Years but return to higher numbers in the interim 4 years... though Gallop poll (Source) did note a higher than significant rise of independents between 2016 and 2017, rising from 39% to 42% (the Zenith of independent identification was in 2014, with 43% of the voter registration).



Generally, the candidate who courts the independents, not the party base, will be the one to win the election.






share|improve this answer


















  • 1




    Re: "aside from the primary elections, there is no benefit to joining a political party": What's more, almost half the states now have open primaries, eliminating even that benefit.
    – ruakh
    Aug 29 at 7:08






  • 1




    What is the "even then" in this first sentence a response/follow-up to?
    – mbrig
    Aug 29 at 22:30










  • I would say that the number of parties represented in Congress/parliament also play a role. If your choice is between belonging to only two parties (or being independent), you are going to disagree with the party line a number of times. If however there are e.g. 7 parties represented in parliament, chances are you ran for a party with whose line you can agree more often.
    – Graipher
    Aug 30 at 6:55










  • @mbrig: This answer started as a response to a comment and was copied and pasted when it was getting less comment-y and more answer-y. Will edit.
    – hszmv
    Aug 30 at 15:08










Your Answer







StackExchange.ready(function()
var channelOptions =
tags: "".split(" "),
id: "475"
;
initTagRenderer("".split(" "), "".split(" "), channelOptions);

StackExchange.using("externalEditor", function()
// Have to fire editor after snippets, if snippets enabled
if (StackExchange.settings.snippets.snippetsEnabled)
StackExchange.using("snippets", function()
createEditor();
);

else
createEditor();

);

function createEditor()
StackExchange.prepareEditor(
heartbeatType: 'answer',
convertImagesToLinks: false,
noModals: false,
showLowRepImageUploadWarning: true,
reputationToPostImages: null,
bindNavPrevention: true,
postfix: "",
noCode: true, onDemand: true,
discardSelector: ".discard-answer"
,immediatelyShowMarkdownHelp:true
);



);













 

draft saved


draft discarded


















StackExchange.ready(
function ()
StackExchange.openid.initPostLogin('.new-post-login', 'https%3a%2f%2fpolitics.stackexchange.com%2fquestions%2f33230%2fcan-one-say-that-us-politicians-are-more-independent-from-their-parties-than-oth%23new-answer', 'question_page');

);

Post as a guest






























3 Answers
3






active

oldest

votes








3 Answers
3






active

oldest

votes









active

oldest

votes






active

oldest

votes








up vote
37
down vote













Traditionally, yes, but not much anymore



One way would be to look at how often members of one party vote the same as members of another party. In this 2015 paper published on PLOS One: The Rise of Partisanship and Super-Cooperators in the U.S. House of Representatives, Andris et.al. do just this with data from 1949-2018:




We define a network of over 5 million pairs of representatives, and compare the mutual agreement rates on legislative decisions between two distinct types of pairs: those from the same party and those formed of members from different parties.




In the plot below (figure 1), the authors plot the probability that 2 representatives will vote the same way on a vote, split by whether they belong to the same party (light grey) or different parties (dark grey). As you can see, from 1949 (the first year studied) through 1981, there is substantial overlap between the 2 distributions, meaning that members of the same party often disagree at a similar rate to members of a different party.



Beginning in the 1980s, however, these peaks separate, showing that representatives are becoming more polarized and more likely to vote with their party.



enter image description here



The takeaway from this is that while, traditionally, US politicians were quite willing to break with their parties and work with members of their opposition, this behavior has all but disappeared in recent decades.






share|improve this answer


















  • 9




    I've seen this before, but it doesn't show how much non-Americans break from their party, so I can't make a comparison.
    – Azor Ahai
    Aug 28 at 22:46






  • 2




    I would be interested in that as well, though obviously it depends on the country. I think what we can say from these data is that US politicians' reputation for independence (from party control) is no longer warranted
    – divibisan
    Aug 29 at 0:01






  • 2




    @MatthieuM Interesting idea, at first I thought that that might not make that big of difference, but this data follows a time frame where the two parties basically switched voter bases and candidates. I assume this would have a confusing effect on this type of data and make drawing conclusions about past political unity difficult.
    – Nathan Cooper
    Aug 29 at 12:15






  • 2




    That's not a sign of strong parties, that's a sign of strong partisanship. vox.com/mischiefs-of-faction/2016/11/3/13512362/…
    – David Rice
    Aug 29 at 14:50






  • 3




    I think the question is "How would one evaluate this claim?" not "is the claim valid" to which this is an excellent answer.
    – UKMonkey
    Aug 30 at 12:16














up vote
37
down vote













Traditionally, yes, but not much anymore



One way would be to look at how often members of one party vote the same as members of another party. In this 2015 paper published on PLOS One: The Rise of Partisanship and Super-Cooperators in the U.S. House of Representatives, Andris et.al. do just this with data from 1949-2018:




We define a network of over 5 million pairs of representatives, and compare the mutual agreement rates on legislative decisions between two distinct types of pairs: those from the same party and those formed of members from different parties.




In the plot below (figure 1), the authors plot the probability that 2 representatives will vote the same way on a vote, split by whether they belong to the same party (light grey) or different parties (dark grey). As you can see, from 1949 (the first year studied) through 1981, there is substantial overlap between the 2 distributions, meaning that members of the same party often disagree at a similar rate to members of a different party.



Beginning in the 1980s, however, these peaks separate, showing that representatives are becoming more polarized and more likely to vote with their party.



enter image description here



The takeaway from this is that while, traditionally, US politicians were quite willing to break with their parties and work with members of their opposition, this behavior has all but disappeared in recent decades.






share|improve this answer


















  • 9




    I've seen this before, but it doesn't show how much non-Americans break from their party, so I can't make a comparison.
    – Azor Ahai
    Aug 28 at 22:46






  • 2




    I would be interested in that as well, though obviously it depends on the country. I think what we can say from these data is that US politicians' reputation for independence (from party control) is no longer warranted
    – divibisan
    Aug 29 at 0:01






  • 2




    @MatthieuM Interesting idea, at first I thought that that might not make that big of difference, but this data follows a time frame where the two parties basically switched voter bases and candidates. I assume this would have a confusing effect on this type of data and make drawing conclusions about past political unity difficult.
    – Nathan Cooper
    Aug 29 at 12:15






  • 2




    That's not a sign of strong parties, that's a sign of strong partisanship. vox.com/mischiefs-of-faction/2016/11/3/13512362/…
    – David Rice
    Aug 29 at 14:50






  • 3




    I think the question is "How would one evaluate this claim?" not "is the claim valid" to which this is an excellent answer.
    – UKMonkey
    Aug 30 at 12:16












up vote
37
down vote










up vote
37
down vote









Traditionally, yes, but not much anymore



One way would be to look at how often members of one party vote the same as members of another party. In this 2015 paper published on PLOS One: The Rise of Partisanship and Super-Cooperators in the U.S. House of Representatives, Andris et.al. do just this with data from 1949-2018:




We define a network of over 5 million pairs of representatives, and compare the mutual agreement rates on legislative decisions between two distinct types of pairs: those from the same party and those formed of members from different parties.




In the plot below (figure 1), the authors plot the probability that 2 representatives will vote the same way on a vote, split by whether they belong to the same party (light grey) or different parties (dark grey). As you can see, from 1949 (the first year studied) through 1981, there is substantial overlap between the 2 distributions, meaning that members of the same party often disagree at a similar rate to members of a different party.



Beginning in the 1980s, however, these peaks separate, showing that representatives are becoming more polarized and more likely to vote with their party.



enter image description here



The takeaway from this is that while, traditionally, US politicians were quite willing to break with their parties and work with members of their opposition, this behavior has all but disappeared in recent decades.






share|improve this answer














Traditionally, yes, but not much anymore



One way would be to look at how often members of one party vote the same as members of another party. In this 2015 paper published on PLOS One: The Rise of Partisanship and Super-Cooperators in the U.S. House of Representatives, Andris et.al. do just this with data from 1949-2018:




We define a network of over 5 million pairs of representatives, and compare the mutual agreement rates on legislative decisions between two distinct types of pairs: those from the same party and those formed of members from different parties.




In the plot below (figure 1), the authors plot the probability that 2 representatives will vote the same way on a vote, split by whether they belong to the same party (light grey) or different parties (dark grey). As you can see, from 1949 (the first year studied) through 1981, there is substantial overlap between the 2 distributions, meaning that members of the same party often disagree at a similar rate to members of a different party.



Beginning in the 1980s, however, these peaks separate, showing that representatives are becoming more polarized and more likely to vote with their party.



enter image description here



The takeaway from this is that while, traditionally, US politicians were quite willing to break with their parties and work with members of their opposition, this behavior has all but disappeared in recent decades.







share|improve this answer














share|improve this answer



share|improve this answer








edited Aug 28 at 21:26

























answered Aug 28 at 20:36









divibisan

457112




457112







  • 9




    I've seen this before, but it doesn't show how much non-Americans break from their party, so I can't make a comparison.
    – Azor Ahai
    Aug 28 at 22:46






  • 2




    I would be interested in that as well, though obviously it depends on the country. I think what we can say from these data is that US politicians' reputation for independence (from party control) is no longer warranted
    – divibisan
    Aug 29 at 0:01






  • 2




    @MatthieuM Interesting idea, at first I thought that that might not make that big of difference, but this data follows a time frame where the two parties basically switched voter bases and candidates. I assume this would have a confusing effect on this type of data and make drawing conclusions about past political unity difficult.
    – Nathan Cooper
    Aug 29 at 12:15






  • 2




    That's not a sign of strong parties, that's a sign of strong partisanship. vox.com/mischiefs-of-faction/2016/11/3/13512362/…
    – David Rice
    Aug 29 at 14:50






  • 3




    I think the question is "How would one evaluate this claim?" not "is the claim valid" to which this is an excellent answer.
    – UKMonkey
    Aug 30 at 12:16












  • 9




    I've seen this before, but it doesn't show how much non-Americans break from their party, so I can't make a comparison.
    – Azor Ahai
    Aug 28 at 22:46






  • 2




    I would be interested in that as well, though obviously it depends on the country. I think what we can say from these data is that US politicians' reputation for independence (from party control) is no longer warranted
    – divibisan
    Aug 29 at 0:01






  • 2




    @MatthieuM Interesting idea, at first I thought that that might not make that big of difference, but this data follows a time frame where the two parties basically switched voter bases and candidates. I assume this would have a confusing effect on this type of data and make drawing conclusions about past political unity difficult.
    – Nathan Cooper
    Aug 29 at 12:15






  • 2




    That's not a sign of strong parties, that's a sign of strong partisanship. vox.com/mischiefs-of-faction/2016/11/3/13512362/…
    – David Rice
    Aug 29 at 14:50






  • 3




    I think the question is "How would one evaluate this claim?" not "is the claim valid" to which this is an excellent answer.
    – UKMonkey
    Aug 30 at 12:16







9




9




I've seen this before, but it doesn't show how much non-Americans break from their party, so I can't make a comparison.
– Azor Ahai
Aug 28 at 22:46




I've seen this before, but it doesn't show how much non-Americans break from their party, so I can't make a comparison.
– Azor Ahai
Aug 28 at 22:46




2




2




I would be interested in that as well, though obviously it depends on the country. I think what we can say from these data is that US politicians' reputation for independence (from party control) is no longer warranted
– divibisan
Aug 29 at 0:01




I would be interested in that as well, though obviously it depends on the country. I think what we can say from these data is that US politicians' reputation for independence (from party control) is no longer warranted
– divibisan
Aug 29 at 0:01




2




2




@MatthieuM Interesting idea, at first I thought that that might not make that big of difference, but this data follows a time frame where the two parties basically switched voter bases and candidates. I assume this would have a confusing effect on this type of data and make drawing conclusions about past political unity difficult.
– Nathan Cooper
Aug 29 at 12:15




@MatthieuM Interesting idea, at first I thought that that might not make that big of difference, but this data follows a time frame where the two parties basically switched voter bases and candidates. I assume this would have a confusing effect on this type of data and make drawing conclusions about past political unity difficult.
– Nathan Cooper
Aug 29 at 12:15




2




2




That's not a sign of strong parties, that's a sign of strong partisanship. vox.com/mischiefs-of-faction/2016/11/3/13512362/…
– David Rice
Aug 29 at 14:50




That's not a sign of strong parties, that's a sign of strong partisanship. vox.com/mischiefs-of-faction/2016/11/3/13512362/…
– David Rice
Aug 29 at 14:50




3




3




I think the question is "How would one evaluate this claim?" not "is the claim valid" to which this is an excellent answer.
– UKMonkey
Aug 30 at 12:16




I think the question is "How would one evaluate this claim?" not "is the claim valid" to which this is an excellent answer.
– UKMonkey
Aug 30 at 12:16










up vote
5
down vote













Basically this is likely to be true (i.e. that US has more dissent) due to the average effect that "personalized electoral rules" (meaning not running on lists like in continental Europe) and the existence of primary elections in US. From https://www.jstor.org/stable/24886188:




I present an individual level, cross-national analysis of institutional effects on legislators' behavior. To this end, I calculated the percentage of times 6,776 legislators from 180 parties in 30 country-sessions voted against the majority of their party. Using this data, I find support for the assertion that the positive effect of personalized electoral rules on dissent levels is mitigated by centralized selections carried out by party leaders, and similarly that the tendency of democratized selection processes (e.g., primaries) to increase legislators' defection levels is moderated by a party-centered electoral environment.




Alas the paper does not contain the individual country data.



There's one 2015 paper that does make a direct US-Europe contrast, alas in somewhat hard-to-grasp terms:




Moises Ostrogorski once denounced political parties for burying diverse concerns of pluralistic societies under monolithic electoral options. E.E. Schattschneider celebrated them for the same reason: organizing choice and ‘responsible party government’ amid pluralistic complexity. Comparativists have found both dynamics in European legislatures: most European parties exhibit the high average levels of voting unity that Schattschneider’s theory implies, but also display rather Ostrogorskian cycles of discipline, stifling dissent on divisive issues at election time. We use comparativists’ tools to explore the dynamics and normative quality of party unity in the different terrain of the US Congress. We find similar cycles of unity in roll-call voting, but in the American context – with more loosely organized parties, especially historically but still today – Ostrogorskian stifling of dissent operates against a less Schattschneiderian background. In comparative perspective, Congressional parties muffle divisive issues more effectively than they deliver governance, with tenuous implications for representation.




They have some plots of cyclical party discipline in the paper, but these aren't comparative (i.e. US only.) They expand a bit more on their comparison with Europe in text:




Although Ostrogorskian fears might seem to originate from party strength, then,
they may actually be most troubling where parties are weak. The comparative work
that inspired our project shows similar cycles in European parties. Yet these parties
presumably offer more Schattschneiderian benefits in return: very high average
unity means that they retain considerable coherence even in the cycle’s troughs, so
that on many issues they translate electoral unity into responsible government.
When we find similar cycles in a US context with lower average unity – and
especially where parties are weakest, before the 1980s and generally in the Senate –
unity may be more deceptive. The lower the average unity, the more the cycles’
troughs challenge delivery of legislative majorities, and thus the more election-time
peaks represent misleading promises to voters. Especially on issues with the highest
prevailing levels of dissent, where our analysis finds the strongest cycles [...],
parties may serve mainly to remove disruptive questions from electoral competition
(as with EU issues in Europe: Parsons and Weber, 2011). When overall unity across
issues is extremely low – as was long typical in the United States – parties with little
capacity to deliver governance might exist largely to construct rhetorical packages and
obfuscate cross-cutting concerns. Troublingly, we found the strongest cycles of dissent
in parties that should, in principle, be best positioned to deliver on their promises
thanks to electoral success and majority control [...]. Certainly, the
record of US majority parties in enacting major campaign promises is weak – moments
like Obamacare, Newt Gingrich’s Contract with America, or Johnson’s Great Society
are exceptions that prove the rule – and ‘weak Ostrogorskian’ parties may thus share
some of the blame typically attributed to divided government. ‘Responsible party
government’ is especially difficult to deliver in the American context, but unfortunately
it seems that Ostrogorskian muffling is somewhat easier to achieve.




So yes, overall they find "lower average [party] unity" in the US compared to Europe. They also confirm the US historical trend toward higher party unity since the 1980s (the topic of divibisan's answer).



They conclude US party unity has not reached European levels based on Rice index comparisons:




Recently, Congressional parties have become more unified than ever – though still
not like European parties.
Until the 1990s, Congressional politics were largely
understood as the opposite of strong party government (Mayhew, 1974). In an
institutional environment of majoritarian elections in single-member districts,
combined with a separately-elected executive, classic models of legislative representation
emphasized individual candidates and their constituencies (Miller and
Stokes, 1963). This changed as the long North–South realignment rearranged party
lines, and as reforms in the 1970s gave party leaders resources to incentivize
discipline (Rohde, 1991; Stonecash, 2006). From a fragmented arena with party
scores on the Rice index of voting unity below 70 in the 1950s and 1960s, unity
peaked in the 110th Congress (2007–09) at 87.25 for the House of Representatives
(84.85 including the Senate).



Yet American party unity remains modest by European standards. One survey of
European data from the 1990s found Rice index scores that approached perfection,
like mean unity across multiple parties of 99.93 in Denmark, 99.33 in France, 99.25
in the United Kingdom, and 99.06 in Belgium (Depauw and Martin, 2009: 105).




The paper also notes somewhere in its intro that




European and American literatures on legislative behavior that have remained strikingly separate.




... which is something that I discovered myself trying find any comparative papers to answer this question...






share|improve this answer






















  • And neither does the author's massive PhD thesis (in which that paper corresponds to chapter 4). And if anyone is interested, there's another PhD thesis with breakout data for European countries.
    – Fizz
    Aug 29 at 1:01















up vote
5
down vote













Basically this is likely to be true (i.e. that US has more dissent) due to the average effect that "personalized electoral rules" (meaning not running on lists like in continental Europe) and the existence of primary elections in US. From https://www.jstor.org/stable/24886188:




I present an individual level, cross-national analysis of institutional effects on legislators' behavior. To this end, I calculated the percentage of times 6,776 legislators from 180 parties in 30 country-sessions voted against the majority of their party. Using this data, I find support for the assertion that the positive effect of personalized electoral rules on dissent levels is mitigated by centralized selections carried out by party leaders, and similarly that the tendency of democratized selection processes (e.g., primaries) to increase legislators' defection levels is moderated by a party-centered electoral environment.




Alas the paper does not contain the individual country data.



There's one 2015 paper that does make a direct US-Europe contrast, alas in somewhat hard-to-grasp terms:




Moises Ostrogorski once denounced political parties for burying diverse concerns of pluralistic societies under monolithic electoral options. E.E. Schattschneider celebrated them for the same reason: organizing choice and ‘responsible party government’ amid pluralistic complexity. Comparativists have found both dynamics in European legislatures: most European parties exhibit the high average levels of voting unity that Schattschneider’s theory implies, but also display rather Ostrogorskian cycles of discipline, stifling dissent on divisive issues at election time. We use comparativists’ tools to explore the dynamics and normative quality of party unity in the different terrain of the US Congress. We find similar cycles of unity in roll-call voting, but in the American context – with more loosely organized parties, especially historically but still today – Ostrogorskian stifling of dissent operates against a less Schattschneiderian background. In comparative perspective, Congressional parties muffle divisive issues more effectively than they deliver governance, with tenuous implications for representation.




They have some plots of cyclical party discipline in the paper, but these aren't comparative (i.e. US only.) They expand a bit more on their comparison with Europe in text:




Although Ostrogorskian fears might seem to originate from party strength, then,
they may actually be most troubling where parties are weak. The comparative work
that inspired our project shows similar cycles in European parties. Yet these parties
presumably offer more Schattschneiderian benefits in return: very high average
unity means that they retain considerable coherence even in the cycle’s troughs, so
that on many issues they translate electoral unity into responsible government.
When we find similar cycles in a US context with lower average unity – and
especially where parties are weakest, before the 1980s and generally in the Senate –
unity may be more deceptive. The lower the average unity, the more the cycles’
troughs challenge delivery of legislative majorities, and thus the more election-time
peaks represent misleading promises to voters. Especially on issues with the highest
prevailing levels of dissent, where our analysis finds the strongest cycles [...],
parties may serve mainly to remove disruptive questions from electoral competition
(as with EU issues in Europe: Parsons and Weber, 2011). When overall unity across
issues is extremely low – as was long typical in the United States – parties with little
capacity to deliver governance might exist largely to construct rhetorical packages and
obfuscate cross-cutting concerns. Troublingly, we found the strongest cycles of dissent
in parties that should, in principle, be best positioned to deliver on their promises
thanks to electoral success and majority control [...]. Certainly, the
record of US majority parties in enacting major campaign promises is weak – moments
like Obamacare, Newt Gingrich’s Contract with America, or Johnson’s Great Society
are exceptions that prove the rule – and ‘weak Ostrogorskian’ parties may thus share
some of the blame typically attributed to divided government. ‘Responsible party
government’ is especially difficult to deliver in the American context, but unfortunately
it seems that Ostrogorskian muffling is somewhat easier to achieve.




So yes, overall they find "lower average [party] unity" in the US compared to Europe. They also confirm the US historical trend toward higher party unity since the 1980s (the topic of divibisan's answer).



They conclude US party unity has not reached European levels based on Rice index comparisons:




Recently, Congressional parties have become more unified than ever – though still
not like European parties.
Until the 1990s, Congressional politics were largely
understood as the opposite of strong party government (Mayhew, 1974). In an
institutional environment of majoritarian elections in single-member districts,
combined with a separately-elected executive, classic models of legislative representation
emphasized individual candidates and their constituencies (Miller and
Stokes, 1963). This changed as the long North–South realignment rearranged party
lines, and as reforms in the 1970s gave party leaders resources to incentivize
discipline (Rohde, 1991; Stonecash, 2006). From a fragmented arena with party
scores on the Rice index of voting unity below 70 in the 1950s and 1960s, unity
peaked in the 110th Congress (2007–09) at 87.25 for the House of Representatives
(84.85 including the Senate).



Yet American party unity remains modest by European standards. One survey of
European data from the 1990s found Rice index scores that approached perfection,
like mean unity across multiple parties of 99.93 in Denmark, 99.33 in France, 99.25
in the United Kingdom, and 99.06 in Belgium (Depauw and Martin, 2009: 105).




The paper also notes somewhere in its intro that




European and American literatures on legislative behavior that have remained strikingly separate.




... which is something that I discovered myself trying find any comparative papers to answer this question...






share|improve this answer






















  • And neither does the author's massive PhD thesis (in which that paper corresponds to chapter 4). And if anyone is interested, there's another PhD thesis with breakout data for European countries.
    – Fizz
    Aug 29 at 1:01













up vote
5
down vote










up vote
5
down vote









Basically this is likely to be true (i.e. that US has more dissent) due to the average effect that "personalized electoral rules" (meaning not running on lists like in continental Europe) and the existence of primary elections in US. From https://www.jstor.org/stable/24886188:




I present an individual level, cross-national analysis of institutional effects on legislators' behavior. To this end, I calculated the percentage of times 6,776 legislators from 180 parties in 30 country-sessions voted against the majority of their party. Using this data, I find support for the assertion that the positive effect of personalized electoral rules on dissent levels is mitigated by centralized selections carried out by party leaders, and similarly that the tendency of democratized selection processes (e.g., primaries) to increase legislators' defection levels is moderated by a party-centered electoral environment.




Alas the paper does not contain the individual country data.



There's one 2015 paper that does make a direct US-Europe contrast, alas in somewhat hard-to-grasp terms:




Moises Ostrogorski once denounced political parties for burying diverse concerns of pluralistic societies under monolithic electoral options. E.E. Schattschneider celebrated them for the same reason: organizing choice and ‘responsible party government’ amid pluralistic complexity. Comparativists have found both dynamics in European legislatures: most European parties exhibit the high average levels of voting unity that Schattschneider’s theory implies, but also display rather Ostrogorskian cycles of discipline, stifling dissent on divisive issues at election time. We use comparativists’ tools to explore the dynamics and normative quality of party unity in the different terrain of the US Congress. We find similar cycles of unity in roll-call voting, but in the American context – with more loosely organized parties, especially historically but still today – Ostrogorskian stifling of dissent operates against a less Schattschneiderian background. In comparative perspective, Congressional parties muffle divisive issues more effectively than they deliver governance, with tenuous implications for representation.




They have some plots of cyclical party discipline in the paper, but these aren't comparative (i.e. US only.) They expand a bit more on their comparison with Europe in text:




Although Ostrogorskian fears might seem to originate from party strength, then,
they may actually be most troubling where parties are weak. The comparative work
that inspired our project shows similar cycles in European parties. Yet these parties
presumably offer more Schattschneiderian benefits in return: very high average
unity means that they retain considerable coherence even in the cycle’s troughs, so
that on many issues they translate electoral unity into responsible government.
When we find similar cycles in a US context with lower average unity – and
especially where parties are weakest, before the 1980s and generally in the Senate –
unity may be more deceptive. The lower the average unity, the more the cycles’
troughs challenge delivery of legislative majorities, and thus the more election-time
peaks represent misleading promises to voters. Especially on issues with the highest
prevailing levels of dissent, where our analysis finds the strongest cycles [...],
parties may serve mainly to remove disruptive questions from electoral competition
(as with EU issues in Europe: Parsons and Weber, 2011). When overall unity across
issues is extremely low – as was long typical in the United States – parties with little
capacity to deliver governance might exist largely to construct rhetorical packages and
obfuscate cross-cutting concerns. Troublingly, we found the strongest cycles of dissent
in parties that should, in principle, be best positioned to deliver on their promises
thanks to electoral success and majority control [...]. Certainly, the
record of US majority parties in enacting major campaign promises is weak – moments
like Obamacare, Newt Gingrich’s Contract with America, or Johnson’s Great Society
are exceptions that prove the rule – and ‘weak Ostrogorskian’ parties may thus share
some of the blame typically attributed to divided government. ‘Responsible party
government’ is especially difficult to deliver in the American context, but unfortunately
it seems that Ostrogorskian muffling is somewhat easier to achieve.




So yes, overall they find "lower average [party] unity" in the US compared to Europe. They also confirm the US historical trend toward higher party unity since the 1980s (the topic of divibisan's answer).



They conclude US party unity has not reached European levels based on Rice index comparisons:




Recently, Congressional parties have become more unified than ever – though still
not like European parties.
Until the 1990s, Congressional politics were largely
understood as the opposite of strong party government (Mayhew, 1974). In an
institutional environment of majoritarian elections in single-member districts,
combined with a separately-elected executive, classic models of legislative representation
emphasized individual candidates and their constituencies (Miller and
Stokes, 1963). This changed as the long North–South realignment rearranged party
lines, and as reforms in the 1970s gave party leaders resources to incentivize
discipline (Rohde, 1991; Stonecash, 2006). From a fragmented arena with party
scores on the Rice index of voting unity below 70 in the 1950s and 1960s, unity
peaked in the 110th Congress (2007–09) at 87.25 for the House of Representatives
(84.85 including the Senate).



Yet American party unity remains modest by European standards. One survey of
European data from the 1990s found Rice index scores that approached perfection,
like mean unity across multiple parties of 99.93 in Denmark, 99.33 in France, 99.25
in the United Kingdom, and 99.06 in Belgium (Depauw and Martin, 2009: 105).




The paper also notes somewhere in its intro that




European and American literatures on legislative behavior that have remained strikingly separate.




... which is something that I discovered myself trying find any comparative papers to answer this question...






share|improve this answer














Basically this is likely to be true (i.e. that US has more dissent) due to the average effect that "personalized electoral rules" (meaning not running on lists like in continental Europe) and the existence of primary elections in US. From https://www.jstor.org/stable/24886188:




I present an individual level, cross-national analysis of institutional effects on legislators' behavior. To this end, I calculated the percentage of times 6,776 legislators from 180 parties in 30 country-sessions voted against the majority of their party. Using this data, I find support for the assertion that the positive effect of personalized electoral rules on dissent levels is mitigated by centralized selections carried out by party leaders, and similarly that the tendency of democratized selection processes (e.g., primaries) to increase legislators' defection levels is moderated by a party-centered electoral environment.




Alas the paper does not contain the individual country data.



There's one 2015 paper that does make a direct US-Europe contrast, alas in somewhat hard-to-grasp terms:




Moises Ostrogorski once denounced political parties for burying diverse concerns of pluralistic societies under monolithic electoral options. E.E. Schattschneider celebrated them for the same reason: organizing choice and ‘responsible party government’ amid pluralistic complexity. Comparativists have found both dynamics in European legislatures: most European parties exhibit the high average levels of voting unity that Schattschneider’s theory implies, but also display rather Ostrogorskian cycles of discipline, stifling dissent on divisive issues at election time. We use comparativists’ tools to explore the dynamics and normative quality of party unity in the different terrain of the US Congress. We find similar cycles of unity in roll-call voting, but in the American context – with more loosely organized parties, especially historically but still today – Ostrogorskian stifling of dissent operates against a less Schattschneiderian background. In comparative perspective, Congressional parties muffle divisive issues more effectively than they deliver governance, with tenuous implications for representation.




They have some plots of cyclical party discipline in the paper, but these aren't comparative (i.e. US only.) They expand a bit more on their comparison with Europe in text:




Although Ostrogorskian fears might seem to originate from party strength, then,
they may actually be most troubling where parties are weak. The comparative work
that inspired our project shows similar cycles in European parties. Yet these parties
presumably offer more Schattschneiderian benefits in return: very high average
unity means that they retain considerable coherence even in the cycle’s troughs, so
that on many issues they translate electoral unity into responsible government.
When we find similar cycles in a US context with lower average unity – and
especially where parties are weakest, before the 1980s and generally in the Senate –
unity may be more deceptive. The lower the average unity, the more the cycles’
troughs challenge delivery of legislative majorities, and thus the more election-time
peaks represent misleading promises to voters. Especially on issues with the highest
prevailing levels of dissent, where our analysis finds the strongest cycles [...],
parties may serve mainly to remove disruptive questions from electoral competition
(as with EU issues in Europe: Parsons and Weber, 2011). When overall unity across
issues is extremely low – as was long typical in the United States – parties with little
capacity to deliver governance might exist largely to construct rhetorical packages and
obfuscate cross-cutting concerns. Troublingly, we found the strongest cycles of dissent
in parties that should, in principle, be best positioned to deliver on their promises
thanks to electoral success and majority control [...]. Certainly, the
record of US majority parties in enacting major campaign promises is weak – moments
like Obamacare, Newt Gingrich’s Contract with America, or Johnson’s Great Society
are exceptions that prove the rule – and ‘weak Ostrogorskian’ parties may thus share
some of the blame typically attributed to divided government. ‘Responsible party
government’ is especially difficult to deliver in the American context, but unfortunately
it seems that Ostrogorskian muffling is somewhat easier to achieve.




So yes, overall they find "lower average [party] unity" in the US compared to Europe. They also confirm the US historical trend toward higher party unity since the 1980s (the topic of divibisan's answer).



They conclude US party unity has not reached European levels based on Rice index comparisons:




Recently, Congressional parties have become more unified than ever – though still
not like European parties.
Until the 1990s, Congressional politics were largely
understood as the opposite of strong party government (Mayhew, 1974). In an
institutional environment of majoritarian elections in single-member districts,
combined with a separately-elected executive, classic models of legislative representation
emphasized individual candidates and their constituencies (Miller and
Stokes, 1963). This changed as the long North–South realignment rearranged party
lines, and as reforms in the 1970s gave party leaders resources to incentivize
discipline (Rohde, 1991; Stonecash, 2006). From a fragmented arena with party
scores on the Rice index of voting unity below 70 in the 1950s and 1960s, unity
peaked in the 110th Congress (2007–09) at 87.25 for the House of Representatives
(84.85 including the Senate).



Yet American party unity remains modest by European standards. One survey of
European data from the 1990s found Rice index scores that approached perfection,
like mean unity across multiple parties of 99.93 in Denmark, 99.33 in France, 99.25
in the United Kingdom, and 99.06 in Belgium (Depauw and Martin, 2009: 105).




The paper also notes somewhere in its intro that




European and American literatures on legislative behavior that have remained strikingly separate.




... which is something that I discovered myself trying find any comparative papers to answer this question...







share|improve this answer














share|improve this answer



share|improve this answer








edited Aug 29 at 11:43

























answered Aug 29 at 0:29









Fizz

9,10012266




9,10012266











  • And neither does the author's massive PhD thesis (in which that paper corresponds to chapter 4). And if anyone is interested, there's another PhD thesis with breakout data for European countries.
    – Fizz
    Aug 29 at 1:01

















  • And neither does the author's massive PhD thesis (in which that paper corresponds to chapter 4). And if anyone is interested, there's another PhD thesis with breakout data for European countries.
    – Fizz
    Aug 29 at 1:01
















And neither does the author's massive PhD thesis (in which that paper corresponds to chapter 4). And if anyone is interested, there's another PhD thesis with breakout data for European countries.
– Fizz
Aug 29 at 1:01





And neither does the author's massive PhD thesis (in which that paper corresponds to chapter 4). And if anyone is interested, there's another PhD thesis with breakout data for European countries.
– Fizz
Aug 29 at 1:01











up vote
4
down vote













The fact that the US is huge means that politicians from the same party can have different opinions on policy based on regional issues. A Republican from California is going to have strong opinions that differ from a Republican from Texas. From a general standpoint, aside from the primary elections, there is no benefit to joining a political party in the United States unless you intend to run for elected office. Among your average Citizen, registered independent voters (as opposed to the very unnoteworthy Independent Party) are the fastest growing party affiliation in the United States and hold a 42% share of registered voters in the United States, compared to the 29% Democrat share of affiliations and the 25% Republican share (although these aren't their lowest numbers of support, they are pretty close and nadir for each was within the decade).



Most independents identify as leaning towards one party more than another, but all are dissatisfied with the party's pure platform and would rather not be attached to them. The Independent numbers do generally shrink in Presidential Election Years but return to higher numbers in the interim 4 years... though Gallop poll (Source) did note a higher than significant rise of independents between 2016 and 2017, rising from 39% to 42% (the Zenith of independent identification was in 2014, with 43% of the voter registration).



Generally, the candidate who courts the independents, not the party base, will be the one to win the election.






share|improve this answer


















  • 1




    Re: "aside from the primary elections, there is no benefit to joining a political party": What's more, almost half the states now have open primaries, eliminating even that benefit.
    – ruakh
    Aug 29 at 7:08






  • 1




    What is the "even then" in this first sentence a response/follow-up to?
    – mbrig
    Aug 29 at 22:30










  • I would say that the number of parties represented in Congress/parliament also play a role. If your choice is between belonging to only two parties (or being independent), you are going to disagree with the party line a number of times. If however there are e.g. 7 parties represented in parliament, chances are you ran for a party with whose line you can agree more often.
    – Graipher
    Aug 30 at 6:55










  • @mbrig: This answer started as a response to a comment and was copied and pasted when it was getting less comment-y and more answer-y. Will edit.
    – hszmv
    Aug 30 at 15:08














up vote
4
down vote













The fact that the US is huge means that politicians from the same party can have different opinions on policy based on regional issues. A Republican from California is going to have strong opinions that differ from a Republican from Texas. From a general standpoint, aside from the primary elections, there is no benefit to joining a political party in the United States unless you intend to run for elected office. Among your average Citizen, registered independent voters (as opposed to the very unnoteworthy Independent Party) are the fastest growing party affiliation in the United States and hold a 42% share of registered voters in the United States, compared to the 29% Democrat share of affiliations and the 25% Republican share (although these aren't their lowest numbers of support, they are pretty close and nadir for each was within the decade).



Most independents identify as leaning towards one party more than another, but all are dissatisfied with the party's pure platform and would rather not be attached to them. The Independent numbers do generally shrink in Presidential Election Years but return to higher numbers in the interim 4 years... though Gallop poll (Source) did note a higher than significant rise of independents between 2016 and 2017, rising from 39% to 42% (the Zenith of independent identification was in 2014, with 43% of the voter registration).



Generally, the candidate who courts the independents, not the party base, will be the one to win the election.






share|improve this answer


















  • 1




    Re: "aside from the primary elections, there is no benefit to joining a political party": What's more, almost half the states now have open primaries, eliminating even that benefit.
    – ruakh
    Aug 29 at 7:08






  • 1




    What is the "even then" in this first sentence a response/follow-up to?
    – mbrig
    Aug 29 at 22:30










  • I would say that the number of parties represented in Congress/parliament also play a role. If your choice is between belonging to only two parties (or being independent), you are going to disagree with the party line a number of times. If however there are e.g. 7 parties represented in parliament, chances are you ran for a party with whose line you can agree more often.
    – Graipher
    Aug 30 at 6:55










  • @mbrig: This answer started as a response to a comment and was copied and pasted when it was getting less comment-y and more answer-y. Will edit.
    – hszmv
    Aug 30 at 15:08












up vote
4
down vote










up vote
4
down vote









The fact that the US is huge means that politicians from the same party can have different opinions on policy based on regional issues. A Republican from California is going to have strong opinions that differ from a Republican from Texas. From a general standpoint, aside from the primary elections, there is no benefit to joining a political party in the United States unless you intend to run for elected office. Among your average Citizen, registered independent voters (as opposed to the very unnoteworthy Independent Party) are the fastest growing party affiliation in the United States and hold a 42% share of registered voters in the United States, compared to the 29% Democrat share of affiliations and the 25% Republican share (although these aren't their lowest numbers of support, they are pretty close and nadir for each was within the decade).



Most independents identify as leaning towards one party more than another, but all are dissatisfied with the party's pure platform and would rather not be attached to them. The Independent numbers do generally shrink in Presidential Election Years but return to higher numbers in the interim 4 years... though Gallop poll (Source) did note a higher than significant rise of independents between 2016 and 2017, rising from 39% to 42% (the Zenith of independent identification was in 2014, with 43% of the voter registration).



Generally, the candidate who courts the independents, not the party base, will be the one to win the election.






share|improve this answer














The fact that the US is huge means that politicians from the same party can have different opinions on policy based on regional issues. A Republican from California is going to have strong opinions that differ from a Republican from Texas. From a general standpoint, aside from the primary elections, there is no benefit to joining a political party in the United States unless you intend to run for elected office. Among your average Citizen, registered independent voters (as opposed to the very unnoteworthy Independent Party) are the fastest growing party affiliation in the United States and hold a 42% share of registered voters in the United States, compared to the 29% Democrat share of affiliations and the 25% Republican share (although these aren't their lowest numbers of support, they are pretty close and nadir for each was within the decade).



Most independents identify as leaning towards one party more than another, but all are dissatisfied with the party's pure platform and would rather not be attached to them. The Independent numbers do generally shrink in Presidential Election Years but return to higher numbers in the interim 4 years... though Gallop poll (Source) did note a higher than significant rise of independents between 2016 and 2017, rising from 39% to 42% (the Zenith of independent identification was in 2014, with 43% of the voter registration).



Generally, the candidate who courts the independents, not the party base, will be the one to win the election.







share|improve this answer














share|improve this answer



share|improve this answer








edited Aug 30 at 15:09

























answered Aug 28 at 20:57









hszmv

3,730317




3,730317







  • 1




    Re: "aside from the primary elections, there is no benefit to joining a political party": What's more, almost half the states now have open primaries, eliminating even that benefit.
    – ruakh
    Aug 29 at 7:08






  • 1




    What is the "even then" in this first sentence a response/follow-up to?
    – mbrig
    Aug 29 at 22:30










  • I would say that the number of parties represented in Congress/parliament also play a role. If your choice is between belonging to only two parties (or being independent), you are going to disagree with the party line a number of times. If however there are e.g. 7 parties represented in parliament, chances are you ran for a party with whose line you can agree more often.
    – Graipher
    Aug 30 at 6:55










  • @mbrig: This answer started as a response to a comment and was copied and pasted when it was getting less comment-y and more answer-y. Will edit.
    – hszmv
    Aug 30 at 15:08












  • 1




    Re: "aside from the primary elections, there is no benefit to joining a political party": What's more, almost half the states now have open primaries, eliminating even that benefit.
    – ruakh
    Aug 29 at 7:08






  • 1




    What is the "even then" in this first sentence a response/follow-up to?
    – mbrig
    Aug 29 at 22:30










  • I would say that the number of parties represented in Congress/parliament also play a role. If your choice is between belonging to only two parties (or being independent), you are going to disagree with the party line a number of times. If however there are e.g. 7 parties represented in parliament, chances are you ran for a party with whose line you can agree more often.
    – Graipher
    Aug 30 at 6:55










  • @mbrig: This answer started as a response to a comment and was copied and pasted when it was getting less comment-y and more answer-y. Will edit.
    – hszmv
    Aug 30 at 15:08







1




1




Re: "aside from the primary elections, there is no benefit to joining a political party": What's more, almost half the states now have open primaries, eliminating even that benefit.
– ruakh
Aug 29 at 7:08




Re: "aside from the primary elections, there is no benefit to joining a political party": What's more, almost half the states now have open primaries, eliminating even that benefit.
– ruakh
Aug 29 at 7:08




1




1




What is the "even then" in this first sentence a response/follow-up to?
– mbrig
Aug 29 at 22:30




What is the "even then" in this first sentence a response/follow-up to?
– mbrig
Aug 29 at 22:30












I would say that the number of parties represented in Congress/parliament also play a role. If your choice is between belonging to only two parties (or being independent), you are going to disagree with the party line a number of times. If however there are e.g. 7 parties represented in parliament, chances are you ran for a party with whose line you can agree more often.
– Graipher
Aug 30 at 6:55




I would say that the number of parties represented in Congress/parliament also play a role. If your choice is between belonging to only two parties (or being independent), you are going to disagree with the party line a number of times. If however there are e.g. 7 parties represented in parliament, chances are you ran for a party with whose line you can agree more often.
– Graipher
Aug 30 at 6:55












@mbrig: This answer started as a response to a comment and was copied and pasted when it was getting less comment-y and more answer-y. Will edit.
– hszmv
Aug 30 at 15:08




@mbrig: This answer started as a response to a comment and was copied and pasted when it was getting less comment-y and more answer-y. Will edit.
– hszmv
Aug 30 at 15:08

















 

draft saved


draft discarded















































 


draft saved


draft discarded














StackExchange.ready(
function ()
StackExchange.openid.initPostLogin('.new-post-login', 'https%3a%2f%2fpolitics.stackexchange.com%2fquestions%2f33230%2fcan-one-say-that-us-politicians-are-more-independent-from-their-parties-than-oth%23new-answer', 'question_page');

);

Post as a guest













































































Popular posts from this blog

How to check contact read email or not when send email to Individual?

Bahrain

Postfix configuration issue with fips on centos 7; mailgun relay